Were the outcomes of professionally
arranged adoptions better than the outcomes of independent adoptions?
This was one of the most widely cited comparative studies claiming
to show that they were. It was conducted by two physicians, Catherine
Amatruda (a Yale colleague of Arnold
Gesell’s) and Joseph Baldwin, after the passage in 1943
of a Connecticut law requiring that all adoptions be investigated
by a social agency. Mandatory inquiries of this kind were examples
of the minimum standards that reformers had been
advocating for decades, although this particular statute was considered
inadequate because it did not require that investigations occur
before children were placed.
The study compared 100 independently-placed babies with 100 babies
whose adoptions had been arranged by agencies. Only data gathered
at the time of placement was used, which meant that this research
did not technically qualify as outcome research at all. There were
both practical and ideological reasons for this. The researchers
may have believed that it was too soon to follow up on outcomes
since only a few years had passed. But they also assumed that adoptions
judged “good” at the time of placement would necessary
prove “good” later on. This ignored two key issues that
later studies explored: reliability and validity. Research on reliability
asked whether a meaningful consensus existed about the characteristics
of “good” (or “bad”) placements. Research
on validity tested whether initial placement decisions, reliable
or not, accurately predicted outcomes measured later on.
Amatruda and Baldwin found that each group of 100 adoptions contained
roughly the same proportion of “good” and “bad”
babies and families. Good children were identified on the basis
of normal developmental and mental testing, and so were babies categorized
as “poor adoption risks,” a division that exemplified
the hold eugenics still had on thinking about adoption
qualifications at midcentury. Good homes met “modest standards”
that parents offer “a reasonable modicum of security and stability,
a happy home life and a decent up-bringing for the child.”
Homes that did not do so—because of divorce, alcoholism, criminal
records, drug addiction, or domestic violence—were categorized
as “unsuitable.” The ratio in each group under study
was three (good) to one (bad).
Agency adoptions were not distinguished by access to better human
material. What made them different—and better—was their
record of matching like with like. Agency placements made mistakes
in matching only eight percent of the time, whereas
independent adoptions mismatched twenty-eight percent of the children
and parents. Good children were much likelier to end up in bad homes
and vice-versa when professionals were absent from the adoption
process. These findings, according to Amatruda and Baldwin, were
empirical proof that “social agencies do better adoption placements
than does the well-intentioned or expedient laity.” The naturalness
of matching was so self-evident that Amatruda and
Baldwin never wondered whether “low quality” children
might need “high quality” homes. Matching
itself was their measure of success.
Like other research substantiating the superiority of professionally
managed adoptions, the larger goal was to decrease the avoidable
risks that desperate birth mothers and foolish adopters frequently
took by making it harder for them to arrange unregulated, non-agency
adoptions. In 1957, six years after this research was published,
Connecticut became the second state in the country (after Delaware)
to ban independent adoptions altogether.
|